
Research
Public Finance
-
Relaxing Household Liquidity Constraints through Social Security(with Sylvain Catherine and Max Miller)
Journal of Public Economics 189 (2020): 104243.
More than a quarter of working-age households in the United States do not have sufficient savings to cover their expenditures after a month of unemployment. Recent proposals suggest giving workers early access to a small portion of their future Social Security benefits to finance their consumption during the COVID-19 pandemic. We empirically analyze their impact. Relying on data from the Survey of Consumer Finances, we build a measure of households' expected time to cash shortfall based on the incidence of COVID-induced unemployment. We show that access to 1% of future benefits allows 75% of households to maintain their current consumption for three months in case of unemployment. We then compare the efficacy of access to Social Security benefits to already legislated approaches, including early access to retirement accounts, stimulus relief checks, and expanded unemployment insurance.
Social Security and Trends in Wealth Inequality(with Sylvain Catherine and Max Miller)
Accepted, The Journal of Finance
Recent influential work finds large increases in inequality in the U.S. based on measures of wealth concentration that notably exclude the value of social insurance programs. This paper shows that top wealth shares have not changed much over the last three decades when Social Security is properly accounted for. This is because Social Security wealth increased substantially from $7.2 trillion in 1989 to $40.6 trillion in 2019 and now represents nearly 50% of the wealth of the bottom 90% of the wealth distribution. This finding is robust to potential changes to taxes and benefits in response to system financing concerns. Recent influential work finds large increases in inequality in the U.S., based on measures of wealth concentration that notably exclude the value of social insurance programs. This paper shows that top wealth shares have not changed much over the last three decades when Social Security is properly accounted for. This is because Social Security wealth increased substantially from $7 trillion in 1989 to $39 trillion in 2019 and now represents 49% of the wealth of the bottom 90% of the wealth distribution. This finding is robust to potential changes to taxes and benefits in response to system financing concerns.
Media:The Economist, ProMarket, Economics 21
Social Security and the Racial Wealth Gap(with Sylvain Catherine)
September 21, 2023
Chapter in Diversity, Inclusion, and Inequality: Implications for Retirement Income Security and Policy (eds. Olivia Mitchell and Nikolai Roussanov), forthcoming.
In the United States, the median Black household earns 30 percent less per adult than the median White household, yet the latter has over six times more marketable wealth than the former. We revisit this puzzle by expanding our wealth concept to include the present value of social security payments. Once social security wealth is accounted for, the racial wealth gap has narrowed over the last 30 years. In 1989, the median White American household owned over four times more total wealth than their Black and Hispanic American counterparts, but under twice as much in 2019. We argue for the importance of including social security in our study of wealth inequality, because of the role it plays in shaping the marketable wealth distribution and the recent rise in its value.
-
Interest-Rate Risk and Household Portfolios (with Sylvain Catherine, Max Miller, and James Paron)
January 14, 2024
Reject and resubmit at American Economic Review.
How are households exposed to interest-rate risk? When rates fall, households face lower future expected returns but those holding long-term assets— disproportionately the wealthy and middle-aged—experience capital gains. We study the hedging demand for long-term assets in a portfolio choice model. The optimal interest-rate sensitivity of wealth is hump-shaped over the life cycle. Within cohorts, it increases with wealth and earnings. These predictions fit observed patterns in the United States, suggesting a relatively efficient distribution of interest-rate risk. By protecting workers from rate fluctuations, Social Security limits the welfare consequences of rising wealth inequality when rates fall.
Presentations: WFA, NBER Long-Term Asset Management
Financial Regulation
-
Price Regulation in Two-Sided Markets: Empirical Evidence from Debit Cards (with Vladimir Mukharlyamov)
January 16, 2025
Accepted, The Journal of Financial Economics
This paper provides empirical evidence of a well-known theoretical concern that market failures in two-sided markets are hard to identify and correct. We study the reactions of banks, merchants, and consumers to Dodd-Frank’s Durbin Amendment that lowered interchange fees on debit card transactions. Banks recouped a significant portion of their losses by charging consumers for products that they previously provided for free on the subsidized side of the two-sided market. The accelerated adoption of credit cards with higher interchange fees likely diminished—if not eliminated—merchants’ savings. These effects impede the regulation’s stated objective of enhancing consumers’ welfare through lower retail prices.
Presentations: AFA, NBER SI Household Finance, Booth Conference on Financial Regulation*, NYU Stern Women in Finance, Philadelphia Federal Reserve Consumer Finance Conference, Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, Society for Empirical Legal Studies (Theodore Eisenberg Prize), Brookings Institute
What Private Equity Does Differently: Evidence from Life Insurance (with Divya Kirti)
July 14, 2023
The Review of Financial Studies 37.1 (2024): 201-230.
This paper studies how private equity creates value and its consequences for consumer welfare in the insurance industry, where PE investments grew tenfold following the financial crisis. PE firms add value through regulatory and tax arbitrage that increases profits relative to their non-PE counterparts. Crucially, the impact on consumer welfare is nuanced: in the short run, consumers benefit from more favorably priced products. But the arbitrage strategy also exposes them to more risk, as annual expected losses scaled by capital buffers rise by 50 percentage points. This creates the possibility of consumer harm in the event of a downturn.
Presentations: NYU/Penn Law & Finance Conference, IMF Annual Conference*, European Financial Association*
July, 2021
Southern California Law Review 94.5 (2021): 1005-1082.
There is widespread consensus that the Great Recession did not have to be as Great as it was: Had regulators acted earlier, its consequences would have been less severe. Two explanations are typically offered for early inaction. The first is that crises occur unexpectedly, so there is little time to respond aggressively. The second is that even regulators who suspected a downturn was imminent lacked the legal authority to intervene. This Article disputes these myths. First, empirical evidence demonstrates that there was over a year between the first tremors in financial markets and the crash. Second, legal analysis illustrates that regulators had at their disposal significant authority to bolster banks. In fact, they used this authority with respect to small banks, but not large, systemically important firms.
There is an alternative explanation for the tepid initial response to the crisis. Regulators’ default is inaction until regulatory measures of bank health signal distress. These measures are slow to update—in many cases, the day before banks failed, their regulatory capital measures suggested no cause for concern. In the absence of significant change, regulators will inevitably be fire-fighting future financial crises ex-post; rather than successfully policing financial markets ex-ante. The next crisis can be prevented. But to do so will require an overhaul of the financial regulatory regime. This Article proposes a way forward. It advocates for automating aggressive action when financial markets indicate that distress is likely. Such reform will finally make costly bank failures a relic of the past.
Presentations: Duke Law & Economics Seminar, Michigan Law & Economics Seminar, Georgetown Law & Economics Seminar
October, 2019
Columbia Law Review 119.6 (2019): 1519-1596.
The financial crisis exposed major fault lines in banking and financial markets more broadly. Policymakers responded with far- reaching regulation that created a new agency—the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau—and 19changed the structure and function of these markets.
Consumer advocates cheered reforms as welfare enhancing, while the financial sector declared that consumers would be harmed by interventions. With a decade of data now available, this Article examines the successes and failures of the consumer finance reform agenda. Specifically, it marshals data from every zip code and bank in the United States to test the efficacy of three of the most significant postcrisis reforms: in the debit, credit, and overdraft markets.
The results are surprising. Despite cosmetic similarities, these reforms had very different outcomes. Two (changes in the credit and overdraft markets) increase consumer welfare, while the other (in the debit market) decreases it. These findings run counter to prior work by prominent legal scholars and encourage reevaluation of our (mis)conceptions about the efficacy of regulation.
The evidence leads to several insights for regulatory design. First, banks regularly levy hidden fees on consumers, obscuring the true cost of financial products. Regulators should restrict such practices. Second, consumer finance markets are regressive: Low-income customers often pay higher prices than their higher-income counterparts. Regulators should address this inequity. Finally, banks tend to discourage regulation by promising their costs will be passed through to consumers. Regulators should not be overly swayed by their dire warnings.
Presentations: University of Pennsylvania Law, University of Virginia Law, Northwestern Law & Economics Seminar, Texas Law & Economics Seminar, Stanford Behavioral Law Workshop, Berkeley Law and Economics Seminar
Understanding Bank Risk through Market Measures (with Lawrence H. Summers)
September 10, 2016
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2016.2 (2016): 57-127.
Since the financial crisis, there have been major changes in the regulation of large banks directed at reducing their risk. Measures of regulatory capital have substantially increased; leverage ratios have been reduced; and stress-testing has sought to further assure safety by raising levels of capital and reducing risk-taking. Standard financial theories predict that such changes would lead to substantial declines in financial market measures of risk. For major banks in the United States and around the world and for midsized banks in the United States, we test this proposition using information on stock price volatility, option-based estimates of future volatility, beta, credit default swaps, price–earnings ratios, and preferred stock yields. To our surprise, we find that financial market information does not bear out the predictions of financial theory. Measures of volatility and risk premiums today are no lower and perhaps somewhat higher than they were prior to the financial crisis. We examine a number of possible explanations for our findings. While financial markets underestimated risk prior to the crisis and regulatory measures of capital are flawed, we believe that the most important explanation for our findings is the dramatic decline in the franchise value of major banks. We highlight that the ratio of the market value of common equity to assets on both a risk-adjusted and risk-unadjusted basis has declined significantly from the precrisis period to the current period for most major banks. As a consequence, banks are more vulnerable to adverse shocks. We argue for taking a dynamic view of capital that recognizes future profits as a source of capital, and urge approaches to financial regulation supervision that will reliably force rapid capital replenishment in difficult times—something that did not take place in the United States in 2008 and is not taking place in Europe today.
What’s in Your Wallet (and What Should the Law Do About it?)
March, 2020
Chicago Law Review 87.2 (2020): 553-594.
In traditional markets, firms can charge prices that are significantly elevated relative to their costs only if there is a market failure. However, this is not true in a two-sided market (like Amazon, Uber, and Mastercard), where firms often subsidize one side of the market and generate revenue from the other. This means consideration of one side of the market in isolation is problematic. The Court embraced this view in Ohio v. American Express, requiring that anticompetitive harm on one side of a two-sided market be weighed against benefits on the other side.
Legal scholars denounce this decision, which, practically, will make it much more difficult to wield antitrust as a tool to rein in two-sided markets. This inability is concerning as two-sided markets are growing in importance. Furthermore, the pricing structures used by platforms can be regressive, with those least well-off subsidizing their affluent and financially-sophisticated counterparts.
In this Article, I argue that consumer protection, rather than antitrust, is best suited to tame two-sided markets. Consumer protection authority allows for intervention on the grounds that platform users create unavoidable externalities for all consumers. The Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (“CFPB”) has broad power to curtail “unfair, abusive, and deceptive practices.” This authority can be used to restrict practices that decrease consumer welfare, like the anti-steering rules at issue in Ohio v. American Express.
Presentations: Chicago Antitrust Symposium, UPenn Faculty Workshop
The Deregulatory Deception(with Cary Coglianese, Stuart Shapiro)
Regulation and Governance, forthcoming
President Donald Trump and his supporters like to point to the positive economic trends the United States experienced prior to the COVID pandemic. They argue that these positive conditions stemmed from the President’s policies, especially his emphasis on deregulation. But what has the Trump Administration really accomplished when it comes to regulation? The answer is much less than the Administration has claimed—and much less than probably most members of the public would surmise. We compare the claims the Administration has made about its deregulatory accomplishments with what the evidence can sustain. Drawing on an original compilation of data on federal regulation from over the last four years, we find three new completed actions appear in agencies’ regulatory agendas for every one that is labeled deregulatory. When we look at just economically significant actions, even on assumptions favorable to the Administration, we find only one deregulatory action for every one action labeled as regulatory. Overall, we find that every claim we examine about the Trump Administration’s deregulatory efforts is either wrong or exaggerated. The reality is that the Trump Administration has done less deregulating than regulating, and its deregulatory actions have not achieved any demonstrable boost to the economy.
Media: The Regulatory Review, Bloomberg
On Market-Based Approaches to the Valuation of Bank Capital (with Lawrence H. Summers)
Handbook of Financial Stress Testing, 2022
In this paper, we build on our prior work to highlight four points. First, stress tests are dependent on regulatory measures of bank capital, which appear to not be a good proxy for economic capital measures that more accurately indicate the risk of insolvency. Second, stress tests have almost come to be seen as a panacea for resolving crises based on the successes of SCAP. We point out that while crisis stress tests were clearly valuable, it is hard to disentangle the role they played in stabilizing the financial sector from other factors like extraordinary fiscal interventions and good fortune. Third, banks perform far worse on a naive market-based stress test than they do on the annual regulatory exercise, which provides suggestive evidence that the regulatory tests are not painting a full picture about financial stability. Finally, we provide some early thoughts on the COVID-19 experience. The disparity between the optimistic view of bank health in recent stress tests and the reality today provides additional evidence that the current exercise is lacking.
Corporate Crime and Punishment: An Empirical Study (with Dorothy Lund)
Texas Law Review, 2021
For many years, law and economics scholars, as well as politicians and regulators, have debated whether corporate punishment chills beneficial corporate activity, or, in the alternative, lets corporate criminals off too easily. In this paper, we take important first steps in addressing these questions. Specifically, we proxy for corporate crime using three novel sources: the Financial Crimes Enforcement Network (FinCEN) Suspicious Activity Reports (SARs), consumer complaints made to the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB), and whistleblower complaints made to the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC). Each source reveals an increase in complaints or reports indicative of corporate misconduct over the past decade. We also examine levels of public company recidivism and find that they are also on the rise. And we document a potential explanation: recidivist companies are much larger than non-recidivist companies, but they receive smaller fines than non-recidivist companies (measured as a percentage of market capitalization and revenue). We conclude by offering recommendations for enforcement agencies and policymakers. In particular, our results suggest that enforcers are unlikely to achieve optimal deterrence using fines alone. Enforcement agencies should therefore consider other ways of securing deterrence, such as by seeking penalties against guilty individuals and the top executives who facilitate their crimes.
Presentations: Corporate Law Academic Series, Yale Law & Economics Seminar*
Media: Corporate Crime Reporter, Columbia Blue Sky Blog
Who Do Credit Cards Reward?
Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 44.3 (2025): 1090-1098
Regulating payments markets is a complex task because these markets are two-sided: a successful network requires adoption by consumers who transact with cards but also merchants who accept cards. That creates the possibility of anticompetitive action on either side of the network: Consumers can be harmed by actions taken by card companies that lower the number of card offerings available for them to choose from and artificially inflate prices, and similarly merchants can be harmed by the lack of ability to shop around for transaction fees that are more competitively priced. The nature of these two-sided markets has created challenges for the court and made it difficult to evaluate the winners and losers of the payment system, to identify market failures, and to make the case for government intervention.
In this short essay, I seek to make four points. First, the credit card industry is highly profitable and the mechanics of the market that create those profit opportunities is not well understood. Second, the credit card market creates a host of regressive cross-subsidies such that high-wealth, rewards card users airline miles are subsidized by those at the bottom of the distribution who are more likely to transact with cash. Third, new technology and payments systems outside of the United States suggest that these issues may resolve themselves in the future as today’s credit card market becomes a thing of the past. Fourth, regulatory interventions are challenging given the complex nature of this market. But recent focus on making it easier for merchants to make clear to consumers the costs that they bear when consumers shop with rewards cards with high processing fees is worthwhile. Overall, I suspect that—due primarily to technological innovation, but also because of potential policy changes—the payments market of the future will evolve to become faster, safer, and cheaper to the consumers and merchants who interact with it.
-
Stressing the Stress Tests (with Til Schuermann)
January 15, 2025
Spring 2023 saw Silicon Valley Bank, Signature Bank, and First Republic experience failure due to predictable rate hikes by the Federal Reserve. Despite the clear success of stress testing as a crisis and peacetime risk management and capital adequacy tool, the series of bank failures and resultant turmoil in the banking system revealed flaws in the stress testing regime that today governs the regulatory capital regime. It’s clear from these recent events that the current stress testing system is ill-suited to mitigate risk associated with the banking system, especially when looking at smaller regional banks that aren’t subjugated to annual stress testing. Stress testing as a regulatory tool is also exposed to significant legal risks following recent Supreme Court jurisprudence that draws into question the viability of the status quo.
Today, regulators and other interested parties must change tacks to craft a stress testing regime that is fit for purpose. This Article seeks to inform that debate by laying out key features of a successful stress testing program against which we assess the current regime in the US. Based on this analysis, wemakefourspecificrecommendations:1) using multiple scenarios to allow exploration of a wider set of risks; 2) disclosing(stressed) fair value for the assessment of all securities held on banks’ balance sheets; 3) stress testing of funding and liquidity risk; and 4)subjecting more banks to the stress tests. Taken together, these reforms would usefully improve the dynamism of the financial regulatory regime.
Presentations: Yale Law School, Columbia Law Banking Conference, Yale Program on Financial Stability Conference
Tax / Budget Policy
-
The Inflation Reduction Act’s Impact on Tax Compliance and Fiscal Sustainability (with Mark J. Mazur)
The passage of the Inflation Reduction Act represented a seismic shift in the American economy. It includes funding to generate climate security progress by investing in domestic clean energy production and manufacturing. It makes prescription drugs more affordable to many American families. And it finances these crucial investments largely through a once-in-a-generation investment in the IRS to modernize America’s tax administration and, by doing so, meaningfully increase compliance with U.S. tax laws.
Tax Reform for Progressivity: A Pragmatic Approach (with Lawrence H. Summers and Joe Kupferberg)
Chapter in Tackling the Tax Code: Efficient and Equitable Ways to Raise Revenue, Hamilton Project (2020).
Trends in demographics, national security, economic inequality, and the public debt suggest an urgent need for progressive approaches to raising additional revenue. We propose a suite of tax reforms targeted at improving tax compliance, rationalizing the taxation of corporate profits earned domestically and abroad, eliminating preferential treatment of capital gains, and closing tax loopholes and shelters of which wealthy individuals disproportionately avail themselves. We estimate that these proposals have the potential to raise over $4 trillion in the coming decade. These proposals are comparable on the basis of both potential revenue raised and progressivity with newer and more radical proposals, like wealth taxation and mark-to-market reforms, that have been the focus of much recent attention. Importantly, our agenda is likely to enhance rather than reduce efficiency, is far less costly in terms of political capital, and hews more closely to basic notions of fairness than alternative approaches.
Rethinking How We Score Capital Gains Tax Reform (with Lawrence Summers, Owen Zidar, and Eric Zwick)
Tax Policy and the Economy 36.1 (2022): 1-33.
We argue the revenue potential from increasing tax rates on capital gains may be substantially greater than previously understood. First, many prior studies focus primarily on short-run taxpayer responses, and so miss revenue from gains that are deferred when rates change. Second, the rise of pass-throughs and index funds has shifted the composition of capital gains in recent years, such that the share of gains that are highly elastic to the tax rate has likely declined. If some components are less elastic, then their elasticity should get more weight when scoring big changes because they will comprise more of the remaining tax base. Third, closer parity to income rates would provide a backstop to rest of tax system. Fourth, additional base-broadening reforms, like eliminating stepped-up basis, making charitable giving a realization event, reforming donor advised funds, and limiting opportunity zones to places with the highest poverty rates, will decrease the elasticity of the tax base to rate changes. Overall, we do not think the prevailing assumption of many in the scorekeeping community—that raising rates to top ordinary income levels would raise little revenue—is warranted. A crude calculation illustrates that raising capital gains rates to ordinary income levels could raise hundreds of billions more revenue over a decade than other leading estimates suggest.
The Coming Fiscal Cliff: A Blueprint for Tax Reform in 2025 (with Kim Clausing)
The Hamilton Project 14 (2023).
At the end of 2025, almost all of the individual, estate, and pass-through provisions of the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act (TCJA) will expire. This looming expiration creates an important opportunity to improve tax policy along multiple dimensions at the same time that TCJA provisions are evaluated for possible extension. In this paper, we suggest four key principles to guide tax policy choices in 2025: first, reforms should raise revenue on net, improving fiscal sustainability; second, reforms should respond to persistent inequalities by increasing the progressivity of the tax code; third, reforms should work to reduce tax-based inefficiencies in the code, and finally, reforms should address global collective action problems such as climate change and tax competition. Using these principles as a guide, we then evaluate possible TCJA extensions and consider a menu of revenue-raising reforms that together have the potential to raise about $3.5 trillion over the coming decade, while improving the progressivity and efficiency of the tax system
CBO Recognizes, but Understates, Potential of Tax Compliance Efforts (with Lawrence H. Summers)
Tax Notes Federal 168 (2020): 443-449.
In a July 2020 report, the Congressional Budget Office estimated that modest investments in the IRS would generate somewhere between $60 and $100 billion in additional revenue over a decade. This is qualitatively correct. But quantitatively, the revenue potential is much more significant than the CBO report suggests. We highlight five reasons for the CBO’s underestimation: 1) the scale of the investment in the IRS contemplated is modest and far short of sufficient even to return the IRS budget to 2011 levels; 2) the CBO contemplates a limited range of interventions, excluding entirely progress on information reporting and technological advancements; 3) the estimates assume rapidly diminishing returns to marginal increases in investment; 4) the estimates leave out the effect of increased enforcement on taxpayer decision-making; and 5) the use of the 10-year window means that the long-run benefits of increased enforcement are excluded. We discuss these issues, present an alternative calculation, and conclude that a commitment to restoring tax compliance efforts to historical levels could generate over $1 trillion in the next decade.
Shrinking the Tax Gap: A Comprehensive Approach (with Lawrence H. Summers and Charles Rossotti)
Tax Notes Federal 169 (2020): 1467-1475.
In this short article, we come together to provide some detail about the steps a new administration should take to attack the tax gap. Many useful actions can be taken through near-term executive actions. More fundamental changes are likely to require legislation. These reforms will not only generate major amounts of long-term revenue from taxes already on the books but, equally important, they will create a system that is fairer to the majority of compliant taxpayers and provide a far sounder foundation for our federal tax system, which accounts for close to a fifth of the entire U.S. GDP. Combining the insights of our past work, we reach the conclusion that investing less than $100 billion in the IRS over a decade will generate $1.2 trillion to $1.4 trillion in additional tax revenue, primarily from high-income individuals, who are disproportionately responsible for underpayment of owed tax liabilities.
Tax Reform Project: Seeking Experts’ Ideas for a Better Tax Code (Lawrence H. Summers, Fred T. Goldberg Jr. , and Leslie B. Samuels
Tax Notes Federal 182 (2024): 1027-1029.
There is broad agreement on both sides of the political aisle that today, our tax system is not working the way it should. The upcoming 2025 tax debate will come at a time when the Congressional Budget Office’s latest long-term budget outlook suggests that the nation’s fiscal balance is teetering dangerously out of control, with the annual deficit as a share of GDP projected to nearly double to 10 percent by 2053. Debt as a share of GDP is on track to reach never-before-seen heights at over 180 percent of GDP by 2053. We are heading toward uncharted fiscal territory, which suggests the need for both creative revenue solutions as well as innovative ideas for improving the tax system. This is where the Tax Reform Project (TRP) comes in. Our broad objective is to provide a forum for ideas that could (relatively) easily be implemented in today’s code, drawing on insights from practitioners, academics, and other experts.
-
Broken Budgeting (with Safia Sayed)
April 10, 2024
As peacetime deficits rose over the course of the last half century, policymakers searched for tools to assess how close—or far off—new budget, tax, and spending proposals would bring them to fiscal sustainability. This search led to the birth of modern scorekeeping, a complex and highly technical exercise undertaken by neutral government analysts known as scorekeepers. Over the years, many have criticized the process and questioned the accuracy of scores in particular arenas. This Article offers a more provocative and fulsome take. While ostensibly neutral, the primacy of scorekeeping and scorekeepers has created impediments to legislating a progressive vision of government. Progressive policymaking has at its core government interventions that give society the ability to reap benefits down the line—like investments in children, or in combatting climate change—benefits that accrue in the long-term and are difficult to quantify. Presently, scorekeepers register these types of interventions as costs to the fisc rather than profitable investments, and that hinders their adoption. This is not the fault of scorekeepers, who have limited scope to act outside the rules and parameters set out by the members of Congress they serve. But it is a critique of those rules, which through manipulation and misunderstanding create a process that is far from neutral: instead, one that skews policy outcomes against progressive reforms that invest in future generations and in redressing inequality.
Presentations: Georgetown Tax and Public Policy Workshop, ABA Tax Meetings